Table of Contents
- Buy Microeconomics: Price Discrimination essay paper online
- Examples of Price Discrimination
- Personalized Online Pricing
- Real Estate Negotiations
- College Tuition Fees
- Dynamic Pricing in Ride-Sharing
- Art Auctions
- Volume Discounts
- Tiered Utility Pricing
- Subscription Services
- Early Payment Incentives
- Freemium Business Models
- Age-Based Pricing
- Geographical Pricing
- Time-Based Pricing
- Customer Group Discounts
- Loyalty Programs
- Happy Hours
- First Degree Price Discrimination
- Second Degree Price Discrimination
- Third Degree Price Discrimination
- Conclusion
- Related Free Economics Essays
Price discrimination in economics occurs where a firm sells different units of an output at different prices to different markets, and the price differentials are not based on the marginal costs of production (Wilkinson, 2005, pp 398). There are various forms in which price discrimination occurs, each determined by the degree and conditions under which it occurs:
- First-degree price discrimination: Charging customers the maximum they are willing to pay, eliminating consumer surplus.
- Second-degree price discrimination: Offering discounts based on the quantity purchased or certain customer actions, like collecting coupons.
- Third-degree price discrimination: Charging different prices to different demographic groups, like students or seniors.
The practice can lead to an increase in a firm’s profits by capturing more consumer surplus. However, it also raises questions about fairness and can lead to allocative inefficiency, as prices may exceed marginal costs, leading to a decline in consumer surplus and potentially contributing to increased inequality.
In order for price discrimination to occur, there must be more than one market segment, and the segments must be separated to avoid reselling from one segment to the other. The following paper aims to look at the three degrees of price discrimination and the relation of prices set by the monopolist to elasticity of demand.
Calculate the cost of essay
Examples of Price Discrimination
First-degree price discrimination:
Personalized Online Pricing |
E-commerce websites using algorithms to show different prices to different users based on their browsing and spending patterns. |
Real Estate Negotiations |
Sellers or agents setting the price of properties after assessing the maximum amount a buyer is willing to pay. |
College Tuition Fees |
Universities offering financial aid based on a student’s or family’s financial situation, effectively charging different prices for the same education. |
Dynamic Pricing in Ride-Sharing |
Services like Uber or Lyft adjusting fares for each customer based on demand, traffic, and other real-time factors. |
Art Auctions |
The final selling price of art pieces being determined by the highest amount a bidder is willing to offer. |
Second-degree price discrimination:
Volume Discounts |
Retailers offering lower prices per unit when customers purchase in larger quantities, such as “buy one, get one half off” deals. |
Tiered Utility Pricing |
Utility companies charging a lower rate for electricity, water, or gas beyond a certain usage threshold to encourage more consumption. |
Subscription Services |
Offering basic access at a standard rate, while premium features are available at higher price points, such as streaming services with different membership levels. |
Early Payment Incentives |
Suppliers providing discounts to buyers who pay their invoices early, effectively reducing the price for those willing to pay sooner. |
Freemium Business Models |
Companies offering a basic service for free, while charging for advanced features or add-ons, like software or mobile apps with in-app purchases. |
Phone deals offering the first 100 texts for free, with subsequent texts charged at a different rate. Electricity tariffs set at one rate for initial units, but a lower rate for higher consumption.
Third-degree price discrimination:
Age-Based Pricing |
Movie theaters offering discounted tickets to children and seniors. |
Geographical Pricing |
International editions of textbooks being sold at lower prices in certain countries compared to others. |
Time-Based Pricing |
Hotels charging different rates for rooms depending on the season or day of the week. |
Customer Group Discounts |
Software companies providing reduced prices to educational institutions or non-profit organizations. |
Loyalty Programs |
Retailers giving special discounts and offers to members of their loyalty programs, which are not available to non-members. |
Happy Hours |
Happy hours in pubs where drinks are cheaper during times of lower demand. |
Product versioning (a form of indirect segmentation):
- Airlines offering priority boarding or extra legroom for a higher price.
- Organic or fair trade coffee that is priced higher than regular coffee.
These examples illustrate how businesses use price discrimination to maximize profits by charging different prices based on consumer behavior, time, quantity, and other factors.
First Degree Price Discrimination
First degree price discrimination is also known as perfect price discrimination. In this situation, the producer is expected to know all the market conditions, including how much each customer is prepared to pay for a unit of output. In this kind of discrimination, there is no consumer surplus because it is all transferred to the producer as revenue and profit (Wilkinson, 2005, pp 398). The monopolist takes advantage of the possession of knowledge concerning a consumer’s capability to buy, and therefore ensures they sell the output to the consumer at the highest price possible per unit. In prefect price discrimination is the monopolist can only operate in perfect knowledge of the market conditions. Each customer forms a market of their own, with their individual market forces and therefore determiners for their prices.
The monopolist is comfortable selling to the last buyer as long as their purchase price for the output exceeds the marginal cost of production. This is because the producer is aware that they will make additional sales to other customers which will give him an additional profit (Charkravarty, 2009, pp 354). The monopolist therefore bases the price of the last buyer above the marginal cost of production, and the profit is maximized by the sales made additionally by the producer.
Perfect price discrimination generates the maximum surplus for both the consumer and the producer. However, the consumer surplus is all transferred to the producer, which is just an alteration in the distribution of income. The monopolist therefore maximizes output, and the consumer gets the best value of a price they could possibly afford depending on their income, therefore maximizing the total sum of surplus in the market (Charkravarty, 2009, pp 356).
An example of perfect price discrimination is in the example of medical services, such as gynecologists. A gynecologist may know the wealth status of clients, and therefore be able to charge each client differently for the same service, depending on how much they can afford. It is certain that the clients will most likely not ask each other how much they are charged, or sell services to each other. The clients of the gynecologists cannot treat each other, and therefore the gynecologist is assured that the services provided at particular prices cannot be resold at another price. The gynecologist is therefore able to form perfect price discrimination in the market.
Along with the first order offer - 15% discount, you save extra 10% since we provide 300 words/page instead of 275 words/page
Second Degree Price Discrimination
This kind of price discrimination is based on the concept of quantity of units purchased. The quantities may be split into clusters or group, where each group represents an amount and the price at which each unit in the cluster is purchased; that is a group q1-q2 may be sold at p1 while another group q3-q4 is sold at p2. It is important to note that in second degree price discrimination; the change in price is not usually linear, implying that price does not change proportionately to the number of units purchased. It is for this reason that second degree discrimination is known as non- linear pricing (Charkravaty, 2009, pp 355).
A monopolist may apply this principle in the case of a wholesaler for any type of product. When goods exceeding say fifty units are purchased, they are sold at price P1. When goods sold are above a hundred units, they are sold at price p2, above two hundred units at price p3 and so on. The pricing of the one hundred goods is not necessarily half of p1, and therefore the understanding that the pricing is non linear. It is therefore important for the consumer to understand the segmentation of the monopolist so as to realize the number of units they can purchase.
VIP Services
Extended revision period
$2.00SMS notification of the order status
$3.00Get order proofread by editor
$3.66Get order prepared by top 30 writers
$4.40Get a full PDF plagiarism report
Get VIP support
VIP Service
package $23.23
Second degree price discrimination also occurs when the concept of time is applied (Charkravarty, 2009, pp 354). A monopolist may sell the same units of output to the same market, but have distinct prices depending on the time of purchase. The change in prices is also not proportional to the change in time. For instance, when people enroll in a new institution, those who apply first may be charged less fee, and from a certain time period, a different amount is charged. This means that in our example, those who enrolled a week before others will not be charged half of those who enroll two weeks after.
Third Degree Price Discrimination
Third degree price discrimination is based not on individuals; rather it is based on segments created by the monopolist. The monopolist may find it impossible to know the actual purchasing potential of each customer, but then they may be able to classify the customers into the segments they belong (Wilkinson, 2005 , pp 398). This degree of price discrimination may be disadvantageous in that it may wrongly classify some customers, such that they are totally locked out of the market due to the prices offered in the segment. The producer ends up losing potential consumers of a product as they felt unable to live up to the segment in which they were put.
Book The Best Top Expert at our service
Your order will be assigned to the most experienced writer in the relevant discipline. The highly demanded expert, one of our top-30 writers with the highest rate among the customers.
An example of third degree discrimination is that of the movie theatres. There are special prices for adults because they have less free time and therefore are more elastic. This is because the young viewers have a much more low elasticity of demand, and the monopolist has to create a more attractive price for adults. Should the price of movie tickets be too high, adults will be reluctant to watch them, but it is likely the youth will adjust to the new prices and still watch. The youth in this case are obviously much free to watch the movies, and any price increase exerted upon them will not change their preference to watch the movies.
Principle of third-degree price discrimination, where different prices are set for different groups based on the elasticity of demand:
The monopolist has to decide on the optimal price for the two groups of customers, which is done by equating the marginal cost to the marginal revenue; that is MR=MC (Charkravarty, 2009, pp 354).Determining the elasticity of demand then follows in the equation. The group with a higher elasticity will have a lower price, while the higher price will be set for the group with a lower elasticity of demand. This is given by:
VIP support ensures that your enquiries will be answered immediately by our Support Team. Extra attention is guaranteed.
P1(X1)/p1(X2) =1+ 1/e2/1+1/e1
In this equation:
- ( P_1(X_1) ) and ( P_1(X_2) ) represent the prices charged to two different groups, ( X_1 ) and ( X_2 ), respectively.
- ( e_1 ) and ( e_2 ) represent the price elasticities of demand for the two groups.
Price elasticity of demand measures how sensitive the quantity demanded is to a change in price. A higher elasticity indicates that consumers are more responsive to price changes, while a lower elasticity means they are less responsive.
According to the equation:
- If ( e_2 ) is larger (meaning group ( X_2 ) has a higher elasticity of demand), the denominator ( 1 + \frac{1}{e_1} ) becomes larger, making the fraction smaller, and thus ( P_1(X_1) ) will be lower relative to ( P_1(X_2) ).
- Conversely, if ( e_1 ) is larger (meaning group ( X_1 ) has a higher elasticity), the fraction becomes larger, and ( P_1(X_1) ) will be higher relative to ( P_1(X_2) ).
This reflects the strategy of charging a lower price to the group with a higher elasticity of demand (more price-sensitive) and a higher price to the group with a lower elasticity of demand (less price-sensitive). The goal is to maximize revenue by adjusting prices according to how each group reacts to price changes.
Affiliate Program: Earn 10%
from all orders made by people you bring!
Your people also get 17% discount for their first order
The condition for third degree price discrimination is that the price elasticity must differ for different segments. It must also be impossible for resale to occur between the various segments. Price discrimination is entirely based on the understanding of the monopolist concerning the particular market. The monopolist uses the knowledge concerning the consumers to make decisions on pricing. Third degree price discrimination is entirely based on the price elasticity of demand of the customer in question and the equalization of marginal cost and marginal revenue.
Conclusion
In conclusion, price discrimination is a multifaceted concept in microeconomics that allows firms to charge different prices for the same product based on various criteria. This practice, often aligned with the concept of price discrimination, enables companies to maximize profits by capturing consumer surplus and aligning price more closely with individual willingness to pay. While it can lead to an increase in producer surplus, it must be carefully balanced against the potential marginal cost to consumers who may pay higher prices.
Our Discounts:
5% for more
than 30 pages
10%for more
than 50 pages
15%for more
than 100 pages
Furthermore, price discrimination is a reminder of the delicate interplay between market strategies and economic fairness. The implementation of degree price discrimination requires a nuanced understanding of consumer behavior and market dynamics. It is essential to recognize that while price discrimination can be a powerful tool for revenue maximization, its ethical implications and impact on consumer welfare cannot be overlooked. As such, it remains a pivotal topic in microeconomic analysis, reflecting the ongoing debate over its role in a competitive market economy.